callback( { "result":{ "query":":facetid:toc:\"db/journals/geb/geb104.bht\"", "status":{ "@code":"200", "text":"OK" }, "time":{ "@unit":"msecs", "text":"184.94" }, "completions":{ "@total":"1", "@computed":"1", "@sent":"1", "c":{ "@sc":"45", "@dc":"45", "@oc":"45", "@id":"43439722", "text":":facetid:toc:db/journals/geb/geb104.bht" } }, "hits":{ "@total":"45", "@computed":"45", "@sent":"45", "@first":"0", "hit":[{ "@score":"1", "@id":"2774981", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"48/11118","text":"Mustafa Oguz Afacan"}},"title":"Some further properties of the cumulative offer process.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"656-665","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Afacan17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.006","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.006","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Afacan17"}, "url":"URL#2774981" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2774989", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"204/8052","text":"Antonio A. Arechar"},{"@pid":"187/4453","text":"Anna Dreber"},{"@pid":"63/1841","text":"Drew Fudenberg"},{"@pid":"57/8036","text":"David G. Rand"}]},"title":""I'm just a soul whose intentions are good": The role of communication in noisy repeated games.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"726-743","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/ArecharDFR17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.013","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.013","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/ArecharDFR17"}, "url":"URL#2774989" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2774990", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"93/11415","text":"Itai Arieli"}},"title":"Payoff externalities and social learning.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"392-410","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Arieli17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.005","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.005","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Arieli17"}, "url":"URL#2774990" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2774997", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"32/6259","text":"Oren Ben-Zwi"}},"title":"Walrasian's characterization and a universal ascending auction.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"456-467","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Ben-Zwi17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.013","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.013","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Ben-Zwi17"}, "url":"URL#2774997" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2774999", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"67/655","text":"Dirk Bergemann"},{"@pid":"86/287","text":"Stephen Morris"}]},"title":"Belief-free rationalizability and informational robustness.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"744-759","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/BergemannM17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.014","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.014","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/BergemannM17"}, "url":"URL#2774999" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775001", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"05/9874","text":"Adam Bjorndahl"},{"@pid":"h/JosephYHalpern","text":"Joseph Y. Halpern"},{"@pid":"p/RPass","text":"Rafael Pass"}]},"title":"Reasoning about rationality.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"146-164","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/BjorndahlHP17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.006","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.006","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/BjorndahlHP17"}, "url":"URL#2775001" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775003", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"34/11278","text":"Subir Bose"},{"@pid":"51/11278","text":"Arup Daripa"}]},"title":"Shills and snipes.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"507-516","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/BoseD17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.010","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.010","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/BoseD17"}, "url":"URL#2775003" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775006", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"17/11275","text":"Anat Bracha"},{"@pid":"58/11393","text":"Lise Vesterlund"}]},"title":"Mixed signals: Charity reporting when donations signal generosity and income.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"24-42","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/BrachaV17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.001","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.001","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/BrachaV17"}, "url":"URL#2775006" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775007", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"60/10825","text":"Florian Brandl"}},"title":"The distribution of optimal strategies in symmetric zero-sum games.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"674-680","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Brandl17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.017","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.017","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Brandl17"}, "url":"URL#2775007" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775010", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"184/0990","text":"Peter Buisseret"}},"title":"Electoral competition with entry under non-majoritarian run-off rules.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"494-506","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Buisseret17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.007","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.007","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Buisseret17"}, "url":"URL#2775010" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775015", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"89/8128","text":"Gary Charness"},{"@pid":"204/7836","text":"Chetan Dave"}]},"title":"Confirmation bias with motivated beliefs.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"1-23","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/CharnessD17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.02.015","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.02.015","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/CharnessD17"}, "url":"URL#2775015" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775021", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"147/9228","text":"Subhasish M. Chowdhury"},{"@pid":"33/3218","text":"Sang-Hyun Kim"}]},"title":""Small, yet Beautiful": Reconsidering the optimal design of multi-winner contests.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"486-493","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/ChowdhuryK17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.012","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.012","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/ChowdhuryK17"}, "url":"URL#2775021" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775026", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"191/7238","text":"Simon Dato"},{"@pid":"191/7228","text":"Andreas Grunewald"},{"@pid":"13/204-5","text":"Daniel Müller 0005"},{"@pid":"136/6869","text":"Philipp Strack"}]},"title":"Expectation-based loss aversion and strategic interaction.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"681-705","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/DatoGMS17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.010","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.010","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/DatoGMS17"}, "url":"URL#2775026" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775044", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"45/11283","text":"Daniel F. Garrett"}},"title":"Dynamic mechanism design: Dynamic arrivals and changing values.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"595-612","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Garrett17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.005","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.005","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Garrett17"}, "url":"URL#2775044" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775046", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"150/1160","text":"Alan Gelder"},{"@pid":"92/11117","text":"Dan Kovenock"}]},"title":"Dynamic behavior and player types in majoritarian multi-battle contests.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"444-455","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/GelderK17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.008","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.008","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/GelderK17"}, "url":"URL#2775046" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775048", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"204/7869","text":"Matthew Gentzkow"},{"@pid":"17/2873","text":"Emir Kamenica"}]},"title":"Bayesian persuasion with multiple senders and rich signal spaces.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"411-429","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/GentzkowK17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.004","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.004","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/GentzkowK17"}, "url":"URL#2775048" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775053", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"90/2651","text":"Ronen Gradwohl"},{"@pid":"26/897","text":"Rann Smorodinsky"}]},"title":"Perception games and privacy.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"293-308","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/GradwohlS17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.006","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.006","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/GradwohlS17"}, "url":"URL#2775053" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775054", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"186/1920","text":"Samuel Häfner"}},"title":"A tug-of-war team contest.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"372-391","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Hafner17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.013","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.013","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Hafner17"}, "url":"URL#2775054" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775063", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"204/8056","text":"Toomas Hinnosaar"}},"title":"Calendar mechanisms.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"252-270","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Hinnosaar17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.004","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.004","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Hinnosaar17"}, "url":"URL#2775063" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775068", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"72/8443","text":"Artyom Jelnov"},{"@pid":"65/3126","text":"Yair Tauman"},{"@pid":"86/6928","text":"Richard Zeckhauser"}]},"title":"Attacking the unknown weapons of a potential bomb builder: The impact of intelligence on the strategic interaction.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"177-189","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/JelnovTZ17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.01.006","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.01.006","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/JelnovTZ17"}, "url":"URL#2775068" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775073", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"24/1274","text":"Christian Kellner"},{"@pid":"165/8939","text":"Mark Thordal-Le Quement"}]},"title":"Modes of ambiguous communication.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"271-292","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/KellnerQ17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.010","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.010","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/KellnerQ17"}, "url":"URL#2775073" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775076", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"22/7219","text":"Semin Kim"}},"title":"Ordinal versus cardinal voting rules: A mechanism design approach.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"350-371","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Kim17a","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.012","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.012","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Kim17a"}, "url":"URL#2775076" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775080", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"00/11122","text":"Bettina Klaus"}},"title":"Consistency and its converse for roommate markets.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"43-58","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Klaus17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.002","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.002","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Klaus17"}, "url":"URL#2775080" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775081", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"00/11122","text":"Bettina Klaus"},{"@pid":"49/3037","text":"Flip Klijn"}]},"title":"Non-revelation mechanisms for many-to-many matching: Equilibria versus stability.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"222-229","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/KlausK17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.001","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.001","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/KlausK17"}, "url":"URL#2775081" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775086", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"60/11274","text":"Taro Kumano"}},"title":"Nash implementation of constrained efficient stable matchings under weak priorities.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"230-240","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Kumano17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.003","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.003","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Kumano17"}, "url":"URL#2775086" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775087", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"204/8058","text":"David J. Kusterer"},{"@pid":"94/11118","text":"Patrick W. Schmitz"}]},"title":"The management of innovation: Experimental evidence.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"706-725","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"open","key":"journals/geb/KustererS17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.011","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.011","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/KustererS17"}, "url":"URL#2775087" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775088", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"58/9570","text":"Christoph Kuzmics"}},"title":"Abraham Wald's complete class theorem and Knightian uncertainty.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"666-673","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Kuzmics17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.012","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.012","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Kuzmics17"}, "url":"URL#2775088" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775089", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"204/7872","text":"Maksymilian Kwiek"}},"title":"Efficient voting with penalties.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"468-485","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Kwiek17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.006","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.006","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Kwiek17"}, "url":"URL#2775089" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775090", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"81/5467","text":"Jean-François Laslier"},{"@pid":"54/11406","text":"Matías Núñez"},{"@pid":"95/8503","text":"Carlos Pimienta"}]},"title":"Reaching consensus through approval bargaining.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"241-251","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/LaslierNP17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.002","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.002","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/LaslierNP17"}, "url":"URL#2775090" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775091", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"147/5821","text":"Matt V. Leduc"},{"@pid":"36/5034","text":"Matthew O. Jackson"},{"@pid":"80/1071","text":"Ramesh Johari"}]},"title":"Pricing and referrals in diffusion on networks.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"568-594","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/LeducJJ17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.011","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.011","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/LeducJJ17"}, "url":"URL#2775091" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775095", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"62/6011-4","text":"Jiangtao Li 0004"},{"@pid":"78/437","text":"Rui Tang"}]},"title":"Every random choice rule is backwards-induction rationalizable.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"563-567","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/LiT17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.003","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.003","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/LiT17"}, "url":"URL#2775095" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775100", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"90/11118","text":"Jingfeng Lu"},{"@pid":"74/11282","text":"Sérgio O. Parreiras"}]},"title":"Monotone equilibrium of two-bidder all-pay auctions Redux.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"78-91","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/LuP17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.005","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.005","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/LuP17"}, "url":"URL#2775100" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775103", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"204/7896","text":"Alexander Maas"},{"@pid":"204/8020","text":"Christopher Goemans"},{"@pid":"204/7793","text":"Dale Manning"},{"@pid":"204/7885","text":"Stephan Kroll"},{"@pid":"28/870","text":"Thomas Brown"}]},"title":"Dilemmas, coordination and defection: How uncertain tipping points induce common pool resource destruction.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"760-774","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/MaasGMKB17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.009","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.009","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/MaasGMKB17"}, "url":"URL#2775103" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775104", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"62/11121","text":"Mihai Manea"}},"title":"Bargaining in dynamic markets.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"59-77","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Manea17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.02.014","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.02.014","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Manea17"}, "url":"URL#2775104" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775106", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"50/3848","text":"Daniel Martin"}},"title":"Strategic pricing with rational inattention to quality.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"131-145","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Martin17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.007","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.007","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Martin17"}, "url":"URL#2775106" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775109", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"52/11118","text":"Friederike Mengel"},{"@pid":"50/11424","text":"Javier Rivas"}]},"title":"Common value elections with private information and informative priors: Theory and experiments.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"190-221","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/MengelR17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.009","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.009","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/MengelR17"}, "url":"URL#2775109" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775110", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"204/7794","text":"Rune Midjord"},{"@pid":"98/11274","text":"Tomas Rodriguez-Barraquer"},{"@pid":"204/7892","text":"Justin Valasek"}]},"title":"Voting in large committees with disesteem payoffs: A 'state of the art' model.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"430-443","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/MidjordRV17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.003","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.003","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/MidjordRV17"}, "url":"URL#2775110" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775111", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"149/5762","text":"Saptarshi Mukherjee"},{"@pid":"140/4271","text":"Nozomu Muto"},{"@pid":"07/11283","text":"Eve Ramaekers"}]},"title":"Implementation in undominated strategies with partially honest agents.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"613-631","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/MukherjeeMR17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.014","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.014","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/MukherjeeMR17"}, "url":"URL#2775111" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775113", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"46/11120","text":"Jonathan Newton"}},"title":"Shared intentions: The evolution of collaboration.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"517-534","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Newton17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.001","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.001","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Newton17"}, "url":"URL#2775113" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775114", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"38/6706","text":"Abraham Neyman"}},"title":"Continuous-time stochastic games.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"92-130","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Neyman17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.02.004","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.02.004","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Neyman17"}, "url":"URL#2775114" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775120", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"83/359","text":"Andrés Perea"},{"@pid":"117/4007","text":"Souvik Roy"}]},"title":"A new epistemic characterization of ε-proper rationalizability.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"309-328","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/PereaR17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.009","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.009","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/PereaR17"}, "url":"URL#2775120" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775122", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"154/4242","text":"Trine Tornøe Platz"},{"@pid":"60/8633","text":"Lars Peter Østerdal"}]},"title":"The curse of the first-in-first-out queue discipline.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"165-176","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/PlatzO17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.03.004","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.004","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/PlatzO17"}, "url":"URL#2775122" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775123", "info":{"authors":{"author":[{"@pid":"51/4836","text":"Jérôme Renault"},{"@pid":"40/1668","text":"Eilon Solan"},{"@pid":"88/2336","text":"Nicolas Vieille"}]},"title":"Optimal dynamic information provision.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"329-349","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/RenaultSV17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.04.010","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.04.010","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/RenaultSV17"}, "url":"URL#2775123" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775125", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"09/11118","text":"Frank Rosar"}},"title":"Test design under voluntary participation.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"632-655","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Rosar17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.06.002","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.06.002","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Rosar17"}, "url":"URL#2775125" }, { "@score":"1", "@id":"2775126", "info":{"authors":{"author":{"@pid":"204/7949","text":"Adam Sanjurjo"}},"title":"Search with multiple attributes: Theory and empirics.","venue":"Games Econ. Behav.","volume":"104","pages":"535-562","year":"2017","type":"Journal Articles","access":"closed","key":"journals/geb/Sanjurjo17","doi":"10.1016/J.GEB.2017.05.009","ee":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.009","url":"https://dblp.org/rec/journals/geb/Sanjurjo17"}, "url":"URL#2775126" } ] } } } )